Friday, December 28, 2012

Postwar Europe: 1971-1989


 Postwar Europe: 1971-1989
Western European Politics 
J. Robertson 
25 October 2012

The Age of Despondency and Redress in Europe

In the third section of his book, Tony Judt underscores the continent’s transition from a dichotomy between Eastern and Western Europe into the multilateral political system we see today. To understand the changes of these years, it is necessary to discuss three conditions that provoked public disdain for the ‘eurosclerosis’ that ensued during the 1970s and 1980s. The first deals with Europe’s newfound economic independence from U.S. monetary policy. The second event refers to Europe’s realization of its increasing dependency on the international economic system. The final point addresses the general public’s growing displeasure in the management and administration of its political leaders.
The economic boom of the 1960s was the result of European investments three decades earlier and the U.S.-born Marshall Plan for economic recovery in the post-war years. But by the 1970s, two events provoked a major economic downturn. The first was the U.S. decision to abandon the fixed exchange rate system: the second, the oil crisis after the Yom Kippur War.
In 1971, U.S. president Richard Nixon unilaterally declared the nation’s switch from the fixed exchange rate system to a floating rate system. This change was motivated by increasing Vietnam War costs, a growing federal deficit, and an increasing fear that foreign holders of U.S. currency (including Europe’s central banks) would “seek to exchange their dollars for gold, draining American reserves” (p. 454, Judt).
In Europe, moving to a floating exchange rate “introduced an unprecedented element of uncertainty” away from “the social harmony in the age of rapid growth” during the preceding two decades and afforded by the U.S. funded Marshall Plan (p. 455, Judt). Leaving the 1944 Bretton Woods system caused inflation rates to soar. European governments responded by enacting “deliberately reflationary policies: allowing credit to ease, domestic policies to rise, and their own currencies to fall” (p. 454, Judt). But as prices fell, the costs of imports rose. This trumpeted Europe’s growth, as labor began demanding wage increases from governments that could not keep up with the price ratcheting. Thus, wages remained inert while national leaders scrambled to find another country to replace the U.S. dollar as their market’s standard currency.
The oil crisis of 1973 brought with it even further economic slow down. In the days after the Yom Kippur War began, Egypt and Syria retaliated against the U.S. and Europe for supporting Israel. Major Arab oil-exporting states then imposed oil embargos on Israel’s Western allies. This “increased the price of petroleum by 70 percent” (p. 455, Judt).
This crippled Europeans, whom had grown “accustomed to readily available and remarkably cheap fuel” in the 1960s (p. 455, Judt). The imbalance of low economic growth, coupled with artificially induced price increases caused Europe to enter a decade of unprecedented “‘stagflation’” (p.456, Judt).
Both economic shocks forced Europe to try to resolve these issues as quasi-independent countries. Governments tried to maintain “full employment…compensating in its absence with wage increases for those in work, social transfers for those out of work and cash subsidies” for businesses (p. 460, Judt). But the states soon realized that to remain globally competitive, they needed to establish a transnational “‘snake in a tunnel’: an accord to maintain semi-fixed ratios between their currencies” (p. 461, Judt). This lead to the Economic Monetary System, (EMS), which was to act as a “grid of fixed bilateral exchange rates” underwritten by the “anti-inflationary priorities of the German economy” (p. 461, Judt). This effectively deprived “governments of their initiative in domestic policy” by obliging conformity to multilateral economic practices, but brought economic stability via setting the Deutschmark as the new “currency of reference” (p. 461, Judt).
The third and most salient motivational cause for the revival among EU leaders to form a supranational institution through which European states could coordinate and stabilize their economies relative to each other came from the public backlash of dissatisfaction with current pseudo-independent policies.
The backlash from the hard-hit middle classes came from all over Europe. People began to resent and doubt about the perceived omnipotence of the social welfare state in the wake of stagflation. The abasement of that generation’s sense of social security and political livelihood is best summarized in the following quote:
“It was an age depressingly aware of having come after the big hopes and ambitious
ideas of the recent past, and having nothing to offer but breathless and implausible re-runs and extensions of old thoughts. It was, quite self-consciously, a ‘post-everything’ era, whose future prospects appeared cloudy” (p. 478, Judt).

Yet again in European history, the public felt betrayed by their leaders and the ideologies they espoused. But the 1970s and 1980s were not only strained financial times for the West—in these years the Soviet bloc experienced a dichotomous fall yet further into disparity. By the mid 1980s, “the economy, which had hardly grown through the course of the 1970s, was now actually shrinking: always qualitatively lagging, Soviet output was now quantitatively inadequate as well” (p. 595, Judt).
This continental recession caused Europeans to solidly abandon the tenants of its old canons and replace it with “a new political vernacular-or, rather, a very old one, freshly rediscovered” (p. 564, Judt). That old vernacular was the language of rights and liberties, ideals which were already “inscribed in every European constitution, not least those of the Peoples’ Democracies” (p. 564, Judt).
In the West, this ideological revanchism came via the reappearance of Conservatism and nationalism, as its supporters feared the further secessions of state power to supranational bodies. But while countries such as Northern Ireland, Italy, Spain, and Switzerland abruptly experienced neo-nationalist violence, Western Europe was fortunate to avoid revolution. Most of these campaigns were quelled by negotiating with politicians to achieve their policy goals and soon became marginal national issues.
Overall, “the net effect…was not to polarize society…but rather to deprive politicians of all sides [of the ability] to cluster together in the safety of the middle ground” (p. 477, Judt). No longer could Europe’s citizens so blindly trust their national leaders to protect them from suffering the pitfalls of a rapidly globalizing world economy. 
In the East, however, the rejuvenation of democratic ideals gained momentum for the oncoming demands for Soviet reform. Fed up with the social injustices of the Soviet Union, Czech protestors wrote a petition in 1979. The draft, called “The Charter of Workers’ Rights, ” requested that Moscow correct its mistakes failing to “implement the human rights provisions” of its national constitution, the Helsinki Accords, and the UN’s “covenants on political, civil, economic, and cultural rights, all of which Prague had signed” (p. 569, Judt).
This was an unprecedented effort at Party opposition. Rather than “engaging the Communist authorities, the new opposition was deliberately talking past them” (p. 567, Judt). By presenting their demands as a legal issue, rather than blame their injustices on the incorrigible faults of the Communist system, Party leaders saw no way to circumvent answering their demands without appearing to deliberately ignore fundamental portions of Communist doctrine. Before Communist leaders could stop it, the seeds of resistance were sown anew, and not long afterwards, a series of political debacles forced the reformist Party leader Mikhail Gorbachev to abandon, once and for all, all endeavors to resuscitate his dying state.
Together, these three events symbolize the anticlimactic experience of this period in Europe. The economic slowdown confirmed latent fears that Europeans held about their future during the unprecedented affluence of the 1950s and 1960s. Just as many suspected, the economic growth of those decades was unsustainable, given the infancy of the consumer market, the poorly administered trade practices of the European Economic Community, and the rapidly increasing interdependencies of the European states.
Both the abandonment of the 1944 Bretton Woods system and the Arab oil embargos taught Europeans a valuable lesson about just how sensitive they have become to global economic fluctuations. Such sensitivity seems to be the price for capitalist expansion, and up until these years, Western leaders had romanticized capitalism to the point where it was widely accepted as the ‘guiding savior’ for the ravaged economies in the postwar years. Yet, as with all other doctrines that entered into European colloquium and gained the faith of its citizens, Western Europeans were once again fiscally admonished for over-crediting their nation-based political system as having the ability to bypass any economic contingency. Overall, the peaceful disintegration of Soviet Russia and these economic challenges revived incentives to find a new, more practical approach to solving the increasingly complex problems of a continent headed towards increasing globalization. By 1989, the colloquial stage had indeed been set for fulfilling the post-nationalist goals that had been long sought after by so many leaders in the last century. 

Bibliography
Judt, Tony. Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945. Penguin: New York. 2006. 

No comments:

Post a Comment